In Case of Apocalypse, Follow These 7 Steps

Published in Social Sciences
In Case of Apocalypse, Follow These 7 Steps
Like

When the shit hits the fan, will the selfish survive or will cooperation thrive? We have been interested in how humans behave in times of disaster for over a decade, studying societies around the world to look at how they deal with risk, running experiments in the lab to see how people help (or not) when somebody is in need and using computer simulations to see when generosity is evolutionary viable. 

What we found surprised us. As evolutionarily minded researchers, we expected people to cooperate mostly when they were in situations where they could eventually get paid back for the help they gave. Reciprocity has long been the commonly accepted explanation for cooperation among non-relatives. But that’s not what we found. Instead, what we saw was that people gave generously to others who were in need without expectation of return. The more deeply we studied systems like the osotua system of the Maasai and the kerekere system in Fiji, the clearer it became to us that reciprocity was not the end all be all of human cooperation. Something else was going on, and it wasn’t about keeping accounts and getting paid back.

We eventually realized that the something else that was going on was risk pooling: People were establishing relationships that they could rely on when in need. These systems were based on a sort of informal insurance where people would invest in the relationships and then could call upon their partners for help if an unexpected loss occurred. Among the Maasai, these relationships take the form of what are called osotua (which literally translates as “umbilical cord”) partnerships. Once two people agree to be osotua partners, they have a sacred bond that is governed by rules that, although unwritten, are strict and formal. Osotua gifts are given only in response to a request, and that request must arise from genuine need, for example, livestock losses due to disease, illness, and theft.  

By studying the Maasai and other societies around the world, we have seen that effective risk pooling systems share several key characteristics. We are not alone in noticing that risk pooling systems can enhance community resilience to disasters: anthropologists, economists, and others have documented many systems of risk pooling around the world. We reviewed both our work and the broader literature on risk pooling systems in the article that we published Nature Human Behaviour. We found that successful risk pooling systems followed seven key design principles.

  1. Insures against the unexpected. Participants should agree that the pool is for needs that arise unpredictably, not for routine, predictable needs
  2. There is no obligation to repay. Giving to those in need should not create an obligation for them to repay
  3. Givers are not at risk. Participants should not be not expected to help others until they have taken care of their own needs
  4. Consensus about need. Participants should have a consensus about what constitutes need
  5. Wealth should be visible. Resources should be either naturally visible or made visible to reduce cheating
  6. Partner choice should be allowed. Individuals should be able to decide which partners to accept
  7. Network scale should cover risk. The scale of the network should be large enough to cover the scale of risks

We were inspired by the work of Elinor Ostrom and her collaborators who, in the early 1990s, showed that the tragedy of the commons did not necessarily have to end in tragedy. Rather, many societies around the world had the ability to successfully and collectively govern commons so that they would be maintained in the long term. Ostrom and her colleagues created a list of eight design principles for common pool resource management and shared those through an influential book and set of papers. We hope that this list of design principles for risk pooling systems can be a resource for scholars and students, helping us all go beyond the assumption that generosity requires reciprocity. Because when the shit hits the fan, it turns out it’s the cooperators who thrive.

Please sign in or register for FREE

If you are a registered user on Research Communities by Springer Nature, please sign in

Subscribe to the Topic

Society
Humanities and Social Sciences > Society